Hledat v komentářích
Investiční doporučení
Výsledky společností - ČR
Výsledky společností - Svět
IPO, M&A
Týdenní přehledy
 

Detail - články
China’s Consumer Babies

China’s Consumer Babies

27.11.2013 17:10

China’s leaders have now agreed to relax the country’s decades-old “one-child” policy. Couples now will be permitted to have two children if one parent is an only child (previously, both parents had to be only children), making the new rule applicable to most of the post-1980’s generation that grew up in urban areas. But, while the potential social consequences are obvious, the likely economic impact is less apparent.

When the one-child policy was implemented in 1979 – in an effort to alleviate social, economic, and environmental pressures following the population boom in the 1950’s and 1960’s – the fertility rate plummeted, from three children per household in 1970 to 1.2 in 1982. The household saving rate subsequently soared, from 10.4% in 1983 to a staggering 30.5% in 2011. Could the one-child policy have fueled this rise? If so, will the modified policy precipitate a reversal in this trend and, in turn, a consumption boom in the coming decade?

Rising fertility rates can lower the household saving rate in two main ways. First, children demand increased household expenditure – especially on education, which, for only children aged 15-22, accounts for 15-25% of total Chinese household expenditures (see figure 1). Second, with more children to support them in their old age, parents feel less pressure to save for retirement.

An examination of the spending and saving patterns of households with twins born under the one-child policy suggests that these changes could lead to a drop of 8-9 percentage points in China’s household savings rate – to around 22% – in the coming decades. Because the birth of twins is arguably an exogenous occurrence (unrelated to factors like income and education that affect parents’ decision to have multiple children), comparing households with an only child to those with twins can reveal some of the effects that an additional child has on saving.

From 2002 to 2009, the average saving rate for an only-child household was 21.3%, compared to 12.8% for a household with twins – a difference that holds across all income groups (see table 1). Regression analysis of all urban households in the 1992-2009 period shows that an additional child reduced the saving rate by about 6-7 percentage points. One additional child increased education expenditure (as a percentage of household income) by an average of seven percentage points, food expenditure by 2.5 percentage points, and other spending by roughly 2.7 percentage points.

Intergenerational support – whereby children provide for parents in old age – is not only a social norm; in China, it is stipulated by law. More than half of elderly people’s income derives from family support, which includes financial transfers and in-kind benefits like cohabitation (see figure 2). And the total amount of transfers that parents receive rises with the number of children.

The added security offered by additional offspring means that loosening the one-child policy will probably lead parents to save less on their own, and possibly even to make the kind of risky investments that would be unwise for only-child families. In fact, the one-child policy could be an important reason why, in recent decades, Chinese households have gravitated toward riskless assets. If parents view having a second child as doubling their “safe assets,” they may decide to allocate more of their portfolio toward riskier assets.

It follows that parents of multiple children may also feel secure enough to consume more. On average, the share of household income spent by parents of multiple children on non-child-related consumption in later stages of life is about eight percentage points higher than it is for parents of only children.

The coming demographic shift will also affect national saving. The share of young dependents/borrowers will rise relative to the middle-aged working population. Reducing the proportion of high savers in the economy will tend to lower the aggregate saving rate. The share of elderly people in the population, however, will not change until a generation later.

Though the change to the one-child policy may cause a moderate consumption boom, it could also reverse a positive trend: the acceleration of human-capital accumulation. The typical only child receives significantly more educational investment than the average twin and is 40% more likely to pursue higher education (as opposed to a vocational school). This can likely be explained, in part, by a quantity-quality tradeoff.

Of course, without a clear sense of what China’s natural fertility rate would be, any prediction about the new policy’s impact remains largely speculative. Rising education costs, housing prices, and wages (which increase the opportunity cost of having children) may mean that, even without strict controls, China’s natural fertility rate will not return to the 1970 level. If the average natural rate is currently two children per household, then imposing this restriction will ultimately be welfare-reducing: households that would like to have more than two children will not be able to, while the restriction would be irrelevant to those who want fewer than two children. But the most likely upshot of the policy change will be a moderate baby boom – and better-performing child-related consumer stocks.

Household Saving Rate: Difference in Twins and Only Child Households by Income Group
   Only-Child Households  Twin Households
Average household Saving Rate  21.3% 12.8%
             lowest 20% income quintile 6.4% -2.9%
             second lowest quintile 18.3% 16.6%
             middle income  23.7% 10.3%
             second highest quintile 27.4% 19.5%
             highest 20% quintile 33.4% 25.4%
Source: Urban Household Survey 2002-2009

Jin Keyu is Lecturer in Economics at the London School of Economics.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2013.

Váš názor
Na tomto místě můžete zahájit diskusi. Zatím nebyl zadán žádný názor. Do diskuse mohou přispívat pouze přihlášení uživatelé (Přihlásit). Pokud nemáte účet, na který byste se mohli přihlásit, registrujte se zde.
Aktuální komentáře
31.05.2025
15:22Fidelity International: Co mohou očekávat investoři do technologií?
10:05Víkendář: Cla a nedoceněné přínosy evropské měnové unie
30.05.2025
17:12Která země má nejvíce (čistých) zahraničních aktiv? A jak to souvisí s globálními (ne)rovnováhami?
17:02Trumpova celní politika opět zvedá volatilitu na akciovém trhu  
15:37Lee věří v další růst akcií, pozitivní je i Siegel
14:57ČNB: Český růst byl podpořen investicemi a exportem, výhled zhoršují cla
14:15Čeká nás akciový výprodej? Penzijní fondy se chystají vyvážit portfolia
14:01Trumpovy celní vrtochy už spálily firmám přes 34 miliard dolarů, spočetla agentura Reuters
12:22Perly týdne: TACO, umění vyjednávat a chvíle pro euro
11:54Philip Morris ČR vyplatí za loňský rok dividendu 1220 korun na akcii, stejnou jako loni
10:59Jan Bureš: HDP revidován vzhůru, rok 2025 již bude silný…
10:33Trumpova cla opět platí. A budou platit i zítra? Trhy na zprávy reagují tlumeně  
10:21Zpřesněný odhad HDP za první kvartál ukázal nejrychlejší růst ekonomiky za téměř 3 roky
9:09Rozbřesk: Trumpova cla: platí, neplatí a znovu platí
8:47Bessent: Obchodní rozhovory USA s Čínou váznou, měli by se zapojit prezidenti
8:46Odvolací soud obnovil Trumpova cla
8:44Ministerstvo financí navrhuje zrušit daňový strop 40 milionů, Trumpova cla znovu na scéně a futures jsou smíšené  
6:15Slavný index S&P 500 letos nestíhá. Má smysl začít kupovat akcie mimo USA?
29.05.2025
22:00Nvidia po výsledcích táhla trhy vzhůru  
18:23Nový inflačně - monetární režim a finanční síla obchodovaných firem

Související komentáře
Nejčtenější zprávy dne
Nejčtenější zprávy týdne
Nejdiskutovanější zprávy týdne
Kalendář událostí
Nebyla nalezena žádná data