Hledat v komentářích
Investiční doporučení
Výsledky společností - ČR
Výsledky společností - Svět
IPO, M&A
Týdenní přehledy
 

Detail - články
Lessons from the Fiscal Cliff

Lessons from the Fiscal Cliff

21.01.2013 15:50

One of the many things I learned from Milton Friedman is that the true cost of government is its spending, not its taxes. To put it another way, spending is financed either by current taxes or through borrowing, and borrowing amounts to future taxes, which have almost the same impact on economic performance as current taxes.

We can apply this reasoning to the United States’ unsustainable fiscal deficit. As is well known, closing this deficit requires less spending or more taxes.

The conventional view is that a reasonable, balanced approach entails some of each. But, as Friedman would have argued, the two methods should be considered polar opposites. Less spending means that the government will be smaller. More taxes mean that the government will be larger. Hence, people who favor smaller government (for example, some Republicans) will want the deficit closed entirely by cutting spending, whereas those who favor larger government (for example, President Barack Obama and most Democrats) will want the deficit closed entirely by raising taxes.

As the economist Alberto Alesina has found from studies of fiscal stabilization in OECD countries, eliminating fiscal deficits through spending cuts tends to be much better for the economy than eliminating them through tax increases. A natural interpretation is that spending adjustments work better because they promise smaller government, thereby favoring economic growth.

For a given size of government, the method of raising tax revenue matters. For example, we can choose how much to collect via a general income tax, a payroll tax, a consumption tax (such as a sales or value-added tax), and so on. We can also choose how much revenue to raise today, rather than in the future (by varying the fiscal deficit).

A general principle for an efficient tax system is to collect a given amount of revenue (corresponding in the long run to the government’s spending) in a way that causes as little distortion as possible to the overall economy. Usually, this principle means that marginal tax rates should be similar at different levels of labor income, for various types of consumption, for outlays today versus tomorrow, and so on.

From this perspective, a shortcoming of the US individual income-tax system is that marginal tax rates are high at the bottom (because of means testing of welfare programs) and the top (because of the graduated-rate structure). Thus, the government has moved in the wrong direction since 2009, sharply raising marginal tax rates at the bottom (by dramatically increasing transfer programs) and, more recently, at the top (by raising tax rates on the rich).

One of the most efficient tax-raising methods is the US payroll tax, for which the marginal tax rate is close to the average rate (because deductions are absent and there is little graduation in the rate structure). Therefore, cutting the payroll tax rate in 2011-2012 and making the rate schedule more graduated (on the Medicare side) were mistakes from the standpoint of efficient taxation.

Republicans should consider these ideas when evaluating tax and spending changes in 2013. Going over the “fiscal cliff” would have had the attraction of seriously cutting government spending, although the composition of the cuts – nothing from entitlements and too much from defense – was unattractive. The associated revenue increase was, at least, across the board, rather than the unbalanced hike in marginal tax rates at the top that was enacted.

But the most important part of the deal to avert the fiscal cliff was the restoration of the efficient payroll tax. I estimate that the rise by two percentage points in the amount collected from employees corresponds to about $1.4 trillion in revenue over ten years. This serious revenue boost was not counted in standard reports, because the payroll-tax “holiday” for 2011-2012 had always been treated legally as temporary.

It is true that some macroeconomic modelers, including the Congressional Budget Office, forecasted that going over the cliff would have caused a recession. But those results come from Keynesian models that always predict that GDP expands when the government gets larger. Entirely absent from these models are the negative effects of more government and uncertainty about how fiscal problems will be resolved.

Another recession in the US would not be a great surprise, but it can be attributed to an array of bad government policies and other forces, not to cutting the size of government. Indeed, it is nonsense to think that cuts in government spending should be avoided in the “short run” in order to lower the chance of a recession. If a smaller government is a good idea in the long run (as I believe it is), it is also a good idea in the short run.

Robert J. Barro is Professor of Economics at Harvard University and a senior fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University.

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2013.


Váš názor
Na tomto místě můžete zahájit diskusi. Zatím nebyl zadán žádný názor. Do diskuse mohou přispívat pouze přihlášení uživatelé (Přihlásit). Pokud nemáte účet, na který byste se mohli přihlásit, registrujte se zde.
Aktuální komentáře
16.04.2024
17:48Inflace a sazby v letošním roce – scénář od Bank of America
17:21Stres z výnosů pokračuje a brání akciím se zvednout, banky sentiment nezlepšily  
16:06MMF: Česká ekonomika letos poroste o 0,7 %, světová více než čtyřnásobným tempem
15:45Komentář analytika k Morgan Stanley: Oživení investičního bankovnictví a rostoucí příjmy ze správy majetku  
14:20RMS Mezzanine, a.s.: Přijetí nového úvěru od společnosti JTPEG INVESTMENTSFUND I SICAV, a.s.
14:20ÚOHS povolil skupině Colt CZ nákup výrobce munice Sellier&Bellot
13:56Morgan Stanley (+3 %) posiluje obraz silných výsledků amerických bank díky tradingu i správě aktiv
13:19Obchodníci Bank of America podpořili výsledky, čistý zisk za 1Q skončil v souladu s očekáváním
12:08Důvěra investorů v německou ekonomiku se zlepšila více, než se čekalo
12:06Akcie, které jsou tento týden po výsledcích připravené na divokou jízdu  
11:23Dnešní trhy: Čína nedokáže vyvážit zklamání z amerických sazeb  
9:34Microsoft investuje do AI firmy G42 ze Spojených arabských emirátů
9:05Rozbřesk: Geopolitika opět v centru pozornosti, koruna odolává vyšším sazbám v zahraničí
8:46Avast nesouhlasí s pokutou za neanonymizované údaje, čínská data přinesla smíšený obrázek o ekonomice a evropské futures jsou temně rudé  
8:32Čínská ekonomika ve čtvrtletí meziročně stoupla o 5,3 pct, předčila očekávání
6:35Siegel: Momentum může stále nahrávat velkým technologiím, nakonec se ale projeví valuační diskonty jiných firem
15.04.2024
22:02Wall Street zahájila týden obdobně jako zakončila ten minulý  
17:10Funguje to, ale s použitelností je to horší…
17:05Investoři se začínají víc bát Fedu než Íránu  
16:20Strážce internetového bezpečí Avast dostal pokutu za neoprávněné předávání osobních údajů

Související komentáře
Nejčtenější zprávy dne
Nejčtenější zprávy týdne
Nejdiskutovanější zprávy týdne
Kalendář událostí
ČasUdálost
4:00Čína - HDP, y/y
4:00Čína - Maloobchodní tržby, y/y
4:00Čína - Průmyslová výroba, y/y
11:00DE - Index očekávání ZEW
14:30USA - Počet nově zahájených staveb
15:15USA - Průmyslová výroba, m/m